Abstract
The volatility of expenditures sub-local derived from central government transparency in transfers to local governments may aggravate sublocal economy. This study aims to analyze the effect of fiscal decentralization to the level of volatility of local government spending in 230 sub-local in Indonesia. We use two periods, before and after the implementation of Law No. 28 Year 2009. The regression results indicate that the volatility of local government spending may decrease if the degree of fiscal decentralization increases, especially at the time when districts implement that law. As responsive taxation can provide incentives for smooth spending for sub-local government.
Bahasa Abstract
Volatilitas belanja pemerintah kabupaten/kota yang berasal dari ketidakpastian transfer pemerintah pusat kepada pemerintah daerah dapat memperburuk perekonomian kabupaten/kota. Penelitian ini bertujuan menganalisis pengaruh desentralisasi fiskal terhadap tingkat volatilitas belanja riil pemerintah pada 230 kabupaten/kota di Indonesia serta membandingkan data sebelum dan sesudah implementasi UU No. 28 Tahun 2009. Hasil menunjukkan semakin tinggi derajat desentralisasi fiskal, cenderung menurunkan volatilitas belanja riil pemerintah kabupaten/kota karena kemampuan fiskal kabupaten/kota cenderung meningkat setelah implementasi UU tersebut. Pajak properti merupakan sumber penerimaan daerah yang dapat diprediksi sehingga pemerintah kabupaten/kota dapat mengelola belanja daerahnya dengan lebih pasti dan terukur.
References
[1] Afonso, A., & Furceri, D. (2010). Government size, composition, volatility and economic growth. European Journal of Political Economy, 26(4), 517–532. doi: https: //doi.org/10.1016/j.ejpoleco.2010.02.002.
[2] Akai, N., & Sakata, M. (2002). Fiscal decentralization contributes to economic growth: Evidence from state-level cross-section data for the United State. Journal of Urban Economics, 40(4), 987–1007. doi: https://doi.org/10.1016/S0094- 1190(02)00018-9.
[3] Ashworth, J., Galli, E., & Padovano, F. (2013). Decentralization as a constraint to Leviathan: a panel cointegration analysis. Public Choice, 156(3–4), 491–516. doi: https://doi.org/10.1007/s11127-012-9962-8.
[4] Bergvall, D., Charbit, C., Kraan, D-J., & Merk, O. (2006). Intergovernmental Transfers and Decentralised Public Spending. OECD Working Papers on Fiscal Federalism, 3. Paris: OECD Publishing. doi:http://dx.doi.org/10.1787/5k97b11z2hxwen. Diakses 18 September 2017 dari https://www.oecd-ilibrary.org/taxation/ intergovernmental-transfers-and-decentralised-publicspending 5k97b11z2hxw-en.
[5] Blochliger, H., & Petzold, O. (2009). Taxes and grants: On the revenue mix of sub-central governments. OECD Working Papers on Fiscal Federalism, 7. Paris: OECD Publishing. doi: https://doi.org/10.1787/5k97b11972bn-en. Diakses 18 September 2017 dari https://www.oecd-ilibrary.org/taxation/ taxes-and-grants 5k97b11972bn-en.
[6] Bodman, P., & Hodge, A. (2010). What drives fiscal decentralisation? Further assessing the role of income. Fiscal Studies, 31(3), 373–404. doi: https://doi.org/10.1111/j.1475- 5890.2010.00119.x.
[7] Bordignon, M., & Minelli, E. (2001). Rules transparency and political accountability. Journal of Public Economics, 80(1), 73–98. doi: https://doi.org/10.1016/S0047-2727(00)00109-2.
[8] Borge, L. E., & Rattsø, J. (2008). Property taxation as incentive for cost control: Empirical evidence for utility services in Norway. European Economic Review, 52(6), 1035–1054. doi: https://doi.org/10.1016/j.euroecorev.2007.10.004.
[9] Bradley, R., & Gans, J. S. (1998). Growth in Australian cities. Economic Record, 74(226), 266–278. doi: https://doi.org/10.1111/j.1475-4932.1998.tb01923.x.
[10] Brennan, G., & Buchanan, J. M. (1980). The power to tax: Analytic foundations of a fiscal constitution. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.
[11] Cassette, A., & Paty, S. (2010). Fiscal decentralization and the size of government: A European country empirical analysis. Public Choice, 143(1–2), 173–189.
[12] Charbit, C. (2010). Explaining the sub-national tax-grants balance in OECD countries. OECD Working Papers on Fiscal Federalism, 11. Paris: Organisation for Economic Cooperation and Development (OECD) Publishing. doi: https://doi.org/10.1787/5k97b10s1lq4-en. Diakses 23 September 2017 dari https://www.oecd-ilibrary.org/taxation/ explaining-the-sub-national-tax-grants-balance-in-oecdcountries 5k97b10s1lq4-en.
[13] Eyraud, L. (2014). Reforming capital taxation in Italy. IMF Working Papers, 14/6. International Monetary Fund. Diakses 18 September 2017 dari https://www.imf.org/en/Publications/WP/Issues/2016/12/ 31/Reforming-Capital-Taxation-in-Italy-41258.
[14] Fatas, A., & Mihov, I. (2003). The case for restricting fiscal policy discretion. The Quarterly Journal of Economics, 118(4), 1419–1447. doi: https: //doi.org/10.1162/003355303322552838.
[15] Fatas, A., & Mihov, I. (2005). Policy volatility, institutions and economic growth. CEPR Discussion Papers, 5388. Center for Economic Policy Research. Diakses 25 Agustus 2017 dari https://cepr.org/active/publications/discussion papers/ dp.php?dpno=5388.
[16] Fischel, W. A. (2001). Homevoters, municipal corporate governance, and the benefit view of the property tax. National Tax Journal, 54(1), 157–173.
[17] Fiva, J. H. (2006). New evidence on the effect of fiscal decentralization on the size and composition of government spending. FinanzArchiv/Public Finance Analysis, 62(2), 250– 280.
[18] Fiva, J. H., & Rønning, M. (2008). The incentive effects of property taxation: Evidence from Norwegian school districts. Regional Science and Urban Economics, 38(1), 49–62. doi: https://doi.org/10.1016/j.regsciurbeco.2007.08.008.
[19] Furceri, D. (2007). Is government expenditure volatility harmful for growth? A cross-country analysis. Fiscal Studies, 28(1), 103–120. doi: https://doi.org/10.1111/j.1475- 5890.2007.00049.x.
[20] Furceri, D., & Ribeiro, M. P. (2009). Government consumption volatility and the size of nations. OECD Economics Department Working Papers, 687. Organisation for Economic Cooperation and Development. doi: https://doi.org/10.1787/225543847282. Diakses 15 Agustus 2017 dari https://www.oecd-ilibrary.org/economics/ government-consumption-volatility-and-the-size-of-nations 225543847282.
[21] Furceri, D., Sacchi, A., & Salotti, S. (2016). Can fiscal decentralization alleviate government consumption volatility?. Open Economies Review, 27(4), 611–636. doi: https://doi.org/10.1007/s11079-016-9392-1.
[22] Glaeser, E. L., Kallal, H. D., Scheinkman, J. A., & Shleifer, A. (1992). Growth in cities. Journal of Political Economy, 100(6), 1126–1152. doi: https://doi.org/10.1086/261856.
[23] Golem, S. (2010). Fiscal decentralisation and the size of government: a review of the empirical literature. Financial Theory and Practice, 34(1), 53–69.
[24] Halim, A. (2001). Manajemen keuangan daerah: bunga rampai. Yogyakarta: UPP AMP YKPN.
[25] Haryanto, J. T. (2015, 31 Agustus). Desentralisasi fiskal seutuhnya. Diakses 23 November 2017 dari https://www.kemenkeu.go.id/publikasi/artikel-dan-opini/ desentralisasi-fiskal-seutuhnya.
[26] Jin, J., & Zou, H. F. (2002). How does fiscal decentralization aect aggregate, national, and subnational government size?. Journal of Urban Economics, 52(2), 270–293. doi: https://doi.org/10.1016/S0094-1190(02)00004-9.
[27] Lane, P. R. (2003). The cyclical behaviour of fiscal policy: evidence from the OECD. Journal of Public Economics, 87(12), 2661–2675. doi: https://doi.org/10.1016/S0047- 2727(02)00075-0.
[28] Liberati, P., & Sacchi, A. (2013). Tax decentralization and local government size. Public Choice, 157(1–2), 183–205. doi: https://doi.org/10.1007/s11127-012-9937-9.
[29] Mahi, B. R. (2010). Intergovernmental relations and decentralization in Indonesia: new arrangements and their impacts on local welfare. Economics and Finance in Indonesia, 58(2), 149–172.
[30] Martinez-Vazquez, J., & McNab, R. M. (2003). Fiscal decentralization and economic growth. World Development, 31(9), 1597–1616. doi: https://doi.org/10.1016/S0305- 750X(03)00109-8.
[31] Monkam, N. F. (2012). Fiscal decentralization. South Africa: African Tax Institute Training, Pretoria University.
[32] Musgrave, R. A. (1959). The theory of public finance: A study in public economy. New York: McGraw-Hill.
[33] Musgrave, R. A. (1983). Who should tax, where and what. In C. E. McLure, Jr. (ed.), Tax Assignment in Federal Countries (pp. 2–19). Canberra: Centre for Research on Federal Financial Relations, Australian National University.
[34] Norregaard, J. (2013). Taxing immovable property revenue potential and implementation challenges. IMF Working Papers, 13/129. International Monetary Fund. Diakses 9 Oktober 2017 dari https: //www.imf.org/en/Publications/WP/Issues/2016/12/31/ Taxing-Immovable-Property-Revenue-Potential-and-Implementation- Challenges-40594.
[35] Oates, W. E. (1972). Fiscal federalism. New York: Harcourt Brace.
[36] Oates, W. E., & Schwab, R. M. (1988). Economic competition among jurisdictions: efficiency enhancing or distortion inducing?. Journal of Public Economics, 35(3), 333–354. doi: https://doi.org/10.1016/0047-2727(88)90036-9.
[37] Poterba, J. M. (1995). Balanced budget rules and fiscal policy: Evidence from the states. National Tax Journal, 48(3), 329–336.
[38] Rodden, J. (2003). Reviving Leviathan: fiscal federalism and the growth of government. International Organization, 57(4), 695–729. doi: https://doi.org/10.1017/S0020818303574021.
[39] Rodrik, D. (1998). Why do more open economies have bigger governments?. Journal of Political Economy, 106(5), 997–1032. doi: https://doi.org/10.1086/250038.
[40] Roubini, N., & Sachs, J. (1989). Government spending and budget deficits in the industrial countries. Economic Policy, 4(8), 99–132. doi: https://doi.org/10.2307/1344465.
[41] Sacchi, A., & Salotti, S. (2014). The influence of decentralized taxes and intergovernmental grants on local spending volatility. GEN Working Paper A 2014 – 5. Governance and Economics Research Network, Universidade de Vigo. Diakses 9 Oktober 2017 dari http://infogen.webs.uvigo.es/WP/ WP1405.pdf.
[42] Stein, E. (1999). Fiscal decentralization and government size in Latin America. Journal of Applied Economics, 2(2), 357–391. doi: https://doi.org/10.1080/15140326.1999.12040543.
[43] Stigler, G. J. (1957). The tenable range of functions of local governmnent. In US Congress Joint Economic Committee (Eds.), Federal expenditure policy for economic growth and stability (pp. 213–219). Washington, DC.
[44] Thiessen, U. (2003). Fiscal decentralisation and economic growth in high-income OECD Countries. Fiscal Studies, 24(3), 237–274. doi: https://doi.org/10.1111/j.1475- 5890.2003.tb00084.x.
[45] Tiebout, C. M. (1956). A pure theory of local expenditures. Journal of Political Economy, 64(5), 416-424. doi: https: //doi.org/10.1086/257839.
[46] Weingast, B. R. (2009). Second generation fiscal federalism: The implications of fiscal incentives. Journal of Urban Economics, 65(3), 279–293. doi:https://doi.org/10.1016/j.jue.2008.12.005.
[47] Weingast, B. R. (2014). Second generation fiscal federalism: Political aspects of decentralization and economic development. World Development, 53, 14–25. doi: https: //doi.org/10.1016/j.worlddev.2013.01.003.
Recommended Citation
Mahi, B. Raksaka and Supriyanti, Syarah Siti
(2019)
"Dampak Desentralisasi Fiskal terhadap Volatilitas Belanja Pemerintah Kabupaten/Kota di Indonesia,"
Jurnal Ekonomi dan Pembangunan Indonesia: Vol. 19:
No.
1, Article 7.
DOI: 10.21002/jepi.2019.07
Available at:
https://scholarhub.ui.ac.id/jepi/vol19/iss1/7